Jump to content

Discretionary policy: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
expanding
→‎Arguments against: citation, and elaboration
Line 9: Line 9:
# the need of action and the recognition of that need;
# the need of action and the recognition of that need;
# the recognition of a problem and the design and implementation of a policy response; and
# the recognition of a problem and the design and implementation of a policy response; and
# the implementation of the policy and the effect of the policy.<ref name=Friedman>Friedman, Milton. ''Essays in positive economics'', University of Chicago Press, 1953.</ref>{{rp|145}}
# the implementation of the policy and the effect of the policy.<ref name=Friedman>Friedman, Milton. ''Essays in Positive Economics'', University of Chicago Press, 1953.</ref>{{rp|145}}


It is because of these lags that Friedman argues that discretionary public policy will often be destabilizing. For this reason, he argued the case for general rules rather than discretionary policy.
It is because of these lags that Friedman argues that discretionary public policy will often be destabilizing. For this reason, he argued the case for general rules rather than discretionary policy.


Friedman formalized his argument in the context of monetary policy as follows. The [[quantity equation]] says that
Friedman formalized his argument in the context of monetary policy as follows.<ref>Friedman, Milton. "The effects of a full-employment policy on economic stability: A formal analysis", 1953, pp. 117-132 in Friedman, Milton. ''Essays in Positive Economics'', University of Chicago Press, 1953.</ref> The [[quantity equation]] says that


:<math>MV=Y</math>
:<math>MV=Y</math>
Line 29: Line 29:
:<math>\rho_{mv} < \frac{-\sigma_m}{2\sigma_v}.</math>
:<math>\rho_{mv} < \frac{-\sigma_m}{2\sigma_v}.</math>


Friedman believed that this condition for discretionary policy to be stabilizing is unlikely to be fulfilled in practice, because of the timing problems discussed above.
Thus the monetary authority would have to be sufficiently astute in its policy timing, in trying to counteract anticipated fluctuations in velocity, that the correlation of its money supply changes with velocity changes is not merely negative, not ''sufficiently'' negative to overcome the inherently GDP-variance-magnifying effects of money supply variation. Friedman believed that this condition for discretionary policy to be stabilizing is unlikely to be fulfilled in practice, because of the timing problems discussed above.


==References==
==References==

Revision as of 14:53, 21 August 2014

Discretionary policy is a macroeconomic policy based on the ad hoc judgment of policymakers as opposed to policy set by predetermined rules. For instance, a central banker could make decisions on interest rates on a case-by-case basis instead of allowing a set rule, such as the Taylor rule, to determine interest rates. In practice most policy actions are discretionary in nature.

"Discretionary policy" can refer to decision making in both monetary policy and fiscal policy.

Arguments against

According to Milton Friedman, the dynamics of change associated with the passage of time presents a timing problem for public policy. The reason this poses a problem is because a long and variable time lag exists between:

  1. the need of action and the recognition of that need;
  2. the recognition of a problem and the design and implementation of a policy response; and
  3. the implementation of the policy and the effect of the policy.[1]: 145 

It is because of these lags that Friedman argues that discretionary public policy will often be destabilizing. For this reason, he argued the case for general rules rather than discretionary policy.

Friedman formalized his argument in the context of monetary policy as follows.[2] The quantity equation says that

where M is the money supply, V is the velocity of money, and Y is nominal GDP. Expressing this in growth rates gives

where m, v, and y are the growth rates of the money supply, velocity and nominal GDP respectively. Suppose that the policymaker wishes for the variance of nominal GDP to be as low as possible—that is, it defines a stabilizing approach to monetary policy as one which gives the lowest possible nominal GDP variance. From the last equation we have

where refers to the standard deviation (square root of the variance) of the subscripted variable and refers to the correlation coefficient between the subscripted variables. With no use of discretionary policy or any rule giving fluctuations of the money supply, will equal zero and the target variance will simply be the exogenous variance of velocity, With the use of discretionary policy, on the other hand, all standard deviations in the above equation will be positive, and discretionary policy will have been stabilizing if and only if —that is, if and only if

Thus the monetary authority would have to be sufficiently astute in its policy timing, in trying to counteract anticipated fluctuations in velocity, that the correlation of its money supply changes with velocity changes is not merely negative, not sufficiently negative to overcome the inherently GDP-variance-magnifying effects of money supply variation. Friedman believed that this condition for discretionary policy to be stabilizing is unlikely to be fulfilled in practice, because of the timing problems discussed above.

References

  1. ^ Friedman, Milton. Essays in Positive Economics, University of Chicago Press, 1953.
  2. ^ Friedman, Milton. "The effects of a full-employment policy on economic stability: A formal analysis", 1953, pp. 117-132 in Friedman, Milton. Essays in Positive Economics, University of Chicago Press, 1953.