Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 30

Solution Manual for Principles of Macroeconomics 8th Edition Mankiw

1305971507 9781305971509
Full link download:
Test Bank:
https://testbankpack.com/p/test-bank-for-principles-of-macroeconomics-8th-edition-mankiw-
1305971507-9781305971509/

Solution Manual:
https://testbankpack.com/p/solution-manual-for-principles-of-macroeconomics-8th-edition-
mankiw-1305971507-9781305971509/
w

2 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

WHAT’S NEW IN THE EIGHTH EDITION:


There is a new Ask the Experts feature on "Ticket Resale."

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:
By the end of this chapter, students should understand:

how economists apply the methods of science.

how assumptions and models can shed light on the world.

two simple models—the circular flow and the production possibilities frontier.

the difference between microeconomics and macroeconomics.

the difference between positive and normative statements.

the role of economists in making policy.

why economists sometimes disagree with one another.

CONTEXT AND PURPOSE:


Chapter 2 is the second chapter in a three-chapter section that serves as the introduction of the text.
Chapter 1 introduced ten principles of economics that will be revisited throughout the text. Chapter 2
develops how economists approach problems while Chapter 3 will explain how individuals and countries
gain from trade.
The purpose of Chapter 2 is to familiarize students with how economists approach economic
problems. With practice, they will learn how to approach similar problems in this dispassionate systematic
way. They will see how economists employ the scientific method, the role of assumptions in model
building, and the application of two specific economic models. Students will also learn the important
distinction between two roles economists can play: as scientists when we try to explain the economic
world and as policymakers when we try to improve it.

13
© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
14 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

KEY POINTS:
 Economists try to address their subject with a scientist’s objectivity. Like all scientists, they make
appropriate assumptions and build simplified models to understand the world around them. Two
simple economic models are the circular-flow diagram and the production possibilities frontier.

 The field of economics is divided into two subfields: microeconomics and macroeconomics.
Microeconomists study decision making by households and firms and the interactions among
households and firms in the marketplace. Macroeconomists study the forces and trends that affect
the economy as a whole.

 A positive statement is an assertion about how the world is. A normative statement is an assertion
about how the world ought to be. When economists make normative statements, they are acting
more as policy advisers than as scientists.

 Economists who advise policymakers sometimes offer conflicting advice either because of differences
in scientific judgments or because of differences in values. At other times, economists are united in
the advice they offer, but policymakers may choose to ignore the advice because of the many forces
and constraints imposed by the political process.

CHAPTER OUTLINE:
I. The Economist as Scientist

A. Economists Follow the Scientific Method.

1. Observations help us to develop theory.

2. Data can be collected and analyzed to evaluate theories.

3. Using data to evaluate theories is more difficult in economics than in physical science
because economists are unable to generate their own data and must make do with whatever
data are available.

4. Thus, economists pay close attention to the natural experiments offered by history.

B. Assumptions Make the World Easier to Understand.

1. Example: to understand international trade, it may be helpful to start out assuming that there
are only two countries in the world producing only two goods. Once we understand how
trade would work between these two countries, we can extend our analysis to a greater
number of countries and goods.

2. One important role of a scientist is to understand which assumptions one should make.

3. Economists often use assumptions that are somewhat unrealistic but will have small effects
on the actual outcome of the answer.

C. Economists Use Economic Models to Explain the World around Us.

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist ❖ 15

To illustrate to the class how simple but unrealistic models can be useful, bring a
road map to class. Point out how unrealistic it is. For example, it does not show
where all of the stop signs, gas stations, or restaurants are located. It assumes that
the earth is flat and two-dimensional. But, despite these simplifications, a map
usually helps travelers get from one place to another. Thus, it is a good model.

1. Most economic models are composed of diagrams and equations.

2. The goal of a model is to simplify reality to increase our understanding. Assumptions help to
simplify reality.

D. Our First Model: The Circular Flow Diagram

Figure 1

1. Definition of circular-flow diagram: a visual model of the economy that shows how
dollars flow through markets among households and firms.

2. This diagram is a very simple model of the economy. Note that it ignores the roles of
government and international trade.

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
16 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

a. There are two decision makers in the model: households and firms.

b. There are two markets: the market for goods and services and the market for factors of
production.

c. Firms are sellers in the market for goods and services and buyers in the market for
factors of production.

d. Households are buyers in the market for goods and services and sellers in the market for
factors of production.

e. The inner loop represents the flows of inputs and outputs between households and firms.

f. The outer loop represents the flows of dollars between households and firms.

E. Our Second Model: The Production Possibilities Frontier

1. Definition of production possibilities frontier: a graph that shows the combinations


of output that the economy can possibly produce given the available factors of
production and the available production technology.

Spend more time with this model than you think is necessary. Be aware that students
need to feel confident with this first graphical and mathematical model. Be deliberate
with every point. If you lose them with this model, they may be gone for the rest of
the course.

2. Example: an economy that produces two goods, cars and computers.

a. If all resources are devoted to producing cars, the economy would produce 1,000 cars
and zero computers.

b. If all resources are devoted to producing computers, the economy would produce 3,000
computers and zero cars.

c. More likely, the resources will be divided between the two industries, producing some
cars and some computers. The feasible combinations of output are shown on the
production possibilities frontier.

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist ❖ 17

Figure 2

You may want to include time dimensions for variables. This will help students to
realize that a new production possibilities frontier occurs for each period. The axes
show the levels of output per period.

ALTERNATIVE CLASSROOM EXAMPLE:


A small country produces two goods: mp3 players and music downloads. Points on a
production possibilities frontier can be shown in a table or a graph:

A B C D E
mp3 Players 0 100 200 300 400
Music Downloads 70,000 60,000 45,000 25,000 0

The production possibilities frontier should be drawn from the numbers above.

Students should be asked to calculate the opportunity cost of increasing the number of mp3
players produced by 100:
 between 0 and 100
 between 100 and 200
 between 200 and 300
 between 300 and 400

3. Because resources are scarce, not every combination of computers and cars is possible.
Production at a point outside of the curve (such as C) is not possible given the economy’s
current level of resources and technology.

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
18 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

It is useful to point out that the production possibilities frontier depends on two
things: the availability of resources and the level of technology.

4. Production is efficient at points on the curve (such as A and B). This implies that the
economy is getting all it can from the scarce resources it has available. There is no way to
produce more of one good without producing less of another.

5. Production at a point inside the curve (such as D) is inefficient.

a. This means that the economy is producing less than it can from the resources it has
available.

b. If the source of the inefficiency is eliminated, the economy can increase its production of
both goods.

6. The production possibilities frontier reveals Principle #1: People face trade-offs.

a. Suppose the economy is currently producing 600 cars and 2,200 computers.

b. To increase the production of cars to 700, the production of computers must fall to
2,000.

7. Principle #2 is also shown on the production possibilities frontier: The cost of something is
what you give up to get it (opportunity cost).

a. The opportunity cost of increasing the production of cars from 600 to 700 is 200
computers.

b. Thus, the opportunity cost of each car is two computers.

8. The opportunity cost of a car depends on the number of cars and computers currently
produced by the economy.

a. The opportunity cost of a car is high when the economy is producing many cars and few
computers.

b. The opportunity cost of a car is low when the economy is producing few cars and many
computers.

9. Economists generally believe that production possibilities frontiers often have this bowed-out
shape because some resources are better suited to the production of cars than computers
(and vice versa).

Be aware that students often have trouble understanding why opportunity costs rise
as the production of a good increases. You may want to use several specific
examples of resources that are more suited to producing cars than computers
(e.g., an experienced mechanic) as well as examples of resources that are more
suited to producing computers than cars (e.g., an experienced computer
programmer).

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist ❖ 19

10. The production possibilities frontier can shift if resource availability or technology changes.
Economic growth can be illustrated by an outward shift of the production possibilities
frontier.

Figure 3

You may also want to teach students about budget constraints at this time (call them
“consumption possibilities frontiers”). This reinforces the idea of opportunity cost,
and allows them to see how opportunity cost can be measured by the slope. Also, it
will introduce students to the use of straight-line production possibilities frontiers
(which appear in Chapter 3). However, be careful if you choose to do this as students
often find the difference between straight-line and concave production possibilities
frontiers challenging.

ALTERNATIVE CLASSROOM EXAMPLE:


Ivan receives an allowance from his parents of $20 each week. He spends his entire
allowance on two goods: ice cream cones (which cost $2 each) and tickets to the movies
(which cost $10 each).

Students should be asked to calculate the opportunity cost of one movie and the opportunity
cost of one ice cream cone.

Ivan’s consumption possibilities frontier (budget constraint) can be drawn. It should be noted
that the slope is equal to the opportunity cost and is constant because the opportunity cost is
constant.

Ask students what would happen to the consumption possibilities frontier if Ivan’s allowance
changes or if the price of ice cream cones or movies changes.

F. Microeconomics and Macroeconomics

1. Economics is studied on various levels.

a. Definition of microeconomics: the study of how households and firms make


decisions and how they interact in markets.

b. Definition of macroeconomics: the study of economy-wide phenomena,


including inflation, unemployment, and economic growth.

2. Microeconomics and macroeconomics are closely intertwined because changes in the overall
economy arise from the decisions of individual households and firms.

3. Because microeconomics and macroeconomics address different questions, each field has its
own set of models which are often taught in separate courses.

II. The Economist as Policy Adviser

A. Positive versus Normative Analysis

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
20 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

1. Example of a discussion of minimum-wage laws: Portia says, “Minimum-wage laws cause


unemployment.” Noah says, “The government should raise the minimum wage.”

2. Definition of positive statements: claims that attempt to describe the world as it is.

3. Definition of normative statements: claims that attempt to prescribe how the world
should be.

4. Positive statements can be evaluated by examining data, while normative statements involve
personal viewpoints.

5. Positive views about how the world works affect normative views about which policies are
desirable.

Use several examples to illustrate the differences between positive and normative
statements and stimulate classroom discussion. Possible examples include the
minimum wage, budget deficits, tobacco taxes, legalization of marijuana, and seat-
belt laws.

Have students bring in newspaper articles and in groups, identify each statement in
an editorial paragraph as being a positive or normative statement. Discuss the
differences among news stories, editorials, and blogs and the analogy to economists
as scientists and as policy advisers.

6. Much of economics is positive; it tries to explain how the economy works. But those who use
economics often have goals that are normative. They want to understand how to improve
the economy.

B. Economists in Washington

1. Economists are aware that trade-offs are involved in most policy decisions.

2. The president receives advice from the Council of Economic Advisers (created in 1946).

3. Economists are also employed by administrative departments within the various federal
agencies such as the Office of Management and Budget, the Department of Treasury, the
Department of Labor, the Congressional Budget Office, and the Federal Reserve.

4. The research and writings of economists can also indirectly affect public policy.

C. Why Economists’ Advice Is Not Always Followed

1. The process by which economic policy is made differs from the idealized policy process
assumed in textbooks.

2. Economists offer crucial input into the policy process, but their advice is only part of the
advice received by policymakers.

III. Why Economists Disagree

A. Differences in Scientific Judgments

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist ❖ 21

1. Economists may disagree about the validity of alternative positive theories or about the size
of the effects of changes in the economy on the behavior of households and firms.

2. Example: some economists feel that a change in the tax code that would eliminate a tax on
income and create a tax on consumption would increase saving in this country. However,
other economists feel that the change in the tax system would have little effect on saving
behavior and therefore do not support the change.

B. Differences in Values

C. Perception versus Reality

1. While it seems as if economists do not agree on much, this is in fact not true. Table 1
contains 20 propositions that are endorsed by a majority of economists.

Table 1

2. Almost all economists believe that rent control adversely affects the availability and quality of
housing.

3. Most economists also oppose barriers to trade.

D. Ask the Experts: Ticket Resale

1. The first “Ask the Experts” box shows that 80% of economic experts agree that laws that
limit resale of tickets make potential audience members worse off.

Use the “Ask the Expert” questions and responses from economists throughout the
text to spark discussions. In this case, ask students their opinion on ticket scalping
laws. Discuss the opportunity for potential audience members to pay a price higher
than the stated ticket price to be able to attend the event rather than be excluded
from the event because there are no more tickets available at the stated ticket price.

IV. In the News: Why You Should Study Economics

1. Training in economics helps us to understand fallacies and to anticipate unintended


consequences.

2. This excerpt from a commencement address by Robert D. McTeer, Jr., the former President
of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas describes why students should study economics.

V. Appendix—Graphing: A Brief Review

Many instructors may be unaware of how much trouble beginning students have
grasping the most basic graphs. It is important for instructors to make sure that
students are comfortable with these techniques.

A. Graphs of a Single Variable

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
22 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

Figure A-1

1. Pie Chart

2. Bar Graph

3. Time-Series Graph

B. Graphs of Two Variables: The Coordinate System

Figure A-2

1. Economists are often concerned with relationships between two or more variables.

2. Ordered pairs of numbers can be graphed on a two-dimensional grid.

a. The first number in the ordered pair is the x-coordinate and tells us the horizontal
location of the point.

b. The second number in the ordered pair is the y-coordinate and tells us the vertical
location of the point.

3. The point with both an x-coordinate and y-coordinate of zero is called the origin.

4. Two variables that increase or decrease together have a positive correlation.

5. Two variables that move in opposite directions (one increases when the other decreases)
have a negative correlation.

C. Curves in the Coordinate System

1. Often, economists want to show how one variable affects another, holding all other variables
constant.

Table A-1

Figure A-3

a. An example of this is a demand curve.

b. The demand curve shows how the quantity of a good a consumer wants to purchase
varies as its price varies, holding everything else (such as income) constant.

c. If income does change, this will alter the amount of a good that the consumer wants to
purchase at any given price. Thus, the relationship between price and quantity desired
has changed and must be represented as a new demand curve.

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist ❖ 23

Figure A-4

d. A simple way to tell if it is necessary to shift the curve is to look at the axes. When a
variable that is not named on either axis changes, the curve shifts.

D. Slope

Figure A-5

1. We may want to ask how strongly a consumer reacts if the price of a product changes.

a. If the demand curve is very steep, the quantity desired does not change much in
response to a change in price.

b. If the demand curve is very flat, the quantity desired changes a great deal when the
price changes.

2. The slope of a line is the ratio of the vertical distance covered to the horizontal distance
covered as we move along the line (“rise over run”).

y
slope =
x

3. A small slope (in absolute value) means that the demand curve is relatively flat; a large slope
(in absolute value) means that the demand curve is relatively steep.

E. Cause and Effect

1. Economists often make statements suggesting that a change in Variable A causes a change
in Variable B.

2. Ideally, we would like to see how changes in Variable A affect Variable B, holding all other
variables constant.

3. This is not always possible and could lead to a problem caused by omitted variables.

Figure A-6

a. If Variables A and B both change at the same time, we may conclude that the change in
Variable A caused the change in Variable B.

b. But, if Variable C has also changed, it is entirely possible that Variable C is responsible for
the change in Variable B.

4. Another problem is reverse causality.

Figure A-7

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
24 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

a. If Variable A and Variable B both change at the same time, we may believe that the
change in Variable A led to the change in Variable B.

b. However, it is entirely possible that the change in Variable B led to the change in Variable
A.

c. It is not always as simple as determining which variable changed first because individuals
often change their behavior in response to a change in their expectations about the
future. This means that Variable A may change before Variable B but only because of the
expected change in Variable B.

There are two very good examples in the text that you should use in class. To
discuss the omitted variable problem, point out to students that a rise in the sales of
cigarette lighters is positively related to the number of individuals diagnosed with
lung cancer. To discuss reverse causality, show that an increase in minivan sales is
followed by an increase in birth rates.

SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS:


Quick Quizzes

1. Economics is like a science because economists devise theories, collect data, and analyze the data in
an attempt to verify or refute their theories. In other words, economics is based on the scientific
method.

Figure 1 shows the production possibilities frontier for a society that produces food and clothing.
Point A is an efficient point (on the frontier), point B is an inefficient point (inside the frontier), and
point C is an infeasible point (outside the frontier).

Figure 1

The effects of a drought are shown in Figure 2. The drought reduces the amount of food that can be
produced, shifting the production possibilities frontier inward. (If a drought also reduced the amount

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist ❖ 25

of cotton available for the production of clothing, the intercept on the vertical axis would also
decrease.)

Figure 2

Microeconomics is the study of how households and firms make decisions and how they interact in
markets. Macroeconomics is the study of economy-wide phenomena, including inflation,
unemployment, and economic growth.

2. An example of a positive statement is “a higher price of coffee causes me to buy more tea.” It is a
positive statement because it is a claim that describes the world as it is. An example of a normative
statement is “the government should restrain coffee prices.” It is a normative statement because it is
a claim that prescribes how the world should be. Many other examples are possible.

Parts of the government that regularly rely on advice from economists are the Department of the
Treasury in designing tax policy, the Department of Labor in analyzing data on the employment
situation, the Department of Justice in enforcing the nation’s antitrust laws, the Congressional Budget
Office in evaluating policy proposals, and the Federal Reserve in analyzing economic developments.
Many other answers are possible.

3. Economic advisers to the president might disagree about a question of policy because of differences
in scientific judgments or differences in values.

Chapter Quick Quiz

1. c
2. a
3. b
4. c
5. d
6. a

Questions for Review

1. Economics is a science because economists use the scientific method. They devise theories, collect
data, and then analyze these data in an attempt to verify or refute their theories about how the world

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
26 ❖ Chapter 2/Thinking Like an Economist

works. Economists use theory and observation like other scientists, but they are limited in their ability
to run controlled experiments. Instead, they must rely on natural experiments.

2. Economists make assumptions to simplify problems without substantially affecting the answer.
Assumptions can make the world easier to understand.

3. An economic model cannot describe reality exactly because it would be too complicated to
understand. A model is a simplification that allows the economist to see what is truly important.

4. There are many possible answers.

5. There are many possible answers, including interactions involving government or international trade.

6. Figure 3 shows a production possibilities frontier between milk and cookies (PPF1). If a disease kills
half of the economy's cow population, less milk production is possible, so the PPF shifts inward
(PPF2). Note that if the economy produces all cookies, it does not need any cows and production is
unaffected. But if the economy produces any milk at all, then there will be less production possible
after the disease hits.

Figure 3

7. An outcome is efficient if the economy is getting all it can from the scarce resources it has available.
In terms of the production possibilities frontier, an efficient point is a point on the frontier, such as
point A in Figure 4. When the economy is using its resources efficiently, it cannot increase the
production of one good without reducing the production of the other. A point inside the frontier, such
as point B, is inefficient since more of one good could be produced without reducing the production
of another good.

© 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management
system for classroom use.
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
Pipes instead of Parget for chimneys, either circular for masonry,
or 14 by 9 in., and other forms and sizes, not to injure the bond of
brickwork; Grecian, Italian, pan, plain, and ornamental tiles, instead
of slates, for roofs, with tiles for the hips, valleys, and ridges, a
desirable substitute for lead, those for ridges with pyramidal points,
lilies, &c.; paving tiles, 6, 7½, and 9 in. square, blue and red, to lay in
checquer; skirting tiles; garden edging tiles, very neat; channel tiles;
sough grate tiles; drain shell tiles; conduit pipes, of various
diameters, from 3 to 16 in., with dead or socket joints, also conical,
to fit one within another—the 12 and 16 in. are well adapted fur small
sewers. Great numbers of the different sorts and sizes of these pipes
have been used upon the railways, especially the London and
Birmingham, the Great Western, and Birmingham and Gloucester
lines. At home and abroad they are preferred to lead, iron, &c., to
convey water for domestic use. The paving of this material, whether
square or oblong, is clean, efficient, and durable; it is well adapted
for ground floors in general, for outyards, footpaths in towns, &c.
Bath Depôt—Mr. W. Davey, the Quay.
Bristol Depôt—Mr. G. S. Burroughs, Canon’s-marsh.
Isle of Wight—Mr. Ent. Paxton, Ryde.
An early call is most respectfully solicited.

ORNAMENTAL GLASS, Wedgwood Vases, China and Earthenware.


—APSLEY PELLATT, only surviving partner of the firm of Pellatt and
Green, many years since removed from St. Paul’s churchyard to the
Falcon Glass Works, Holland-street, Blackfriars, which is the only
establishment in London where every operation connected with
glass manufacture (as blowing, cutting, engraving, stoppering, &c.)
may be seen in full operation every Tuesday, Wednesday, and
Thursday. For a description, with engravings, see Penny Magazine,
No. 572. The extensive show-rooms contain a large assortment of
decanters, wine glasses, desert services, toilet and smelling bottles,
medical and philosophical glass ware, crystal renaissance
chandeliers, massive, highly refractive, and decorated with large
arabesque ornamental drops, easily cleaned; also girandoles,
candlesticks, &c. The china and earthenware comprise breakfast,
dinner, desert, tea, and chamber services, from the best
manufacturers; together with an extensive selection of Etruscan,
Italian, and other vases, modelled and executed by the most able
artists at Messrs. Wedgwood’s works, at Etruria, including his
celebrated chef-d’œuvre copy of the largest Etruscan vase in the
British Museum, the Portland vase, &c. Printed lists, with sketches,
may be had on application.

SMITH’S PATENT DOUBLE AND SINGLE ACTION DOOR-


SPRINGS are warranted to be the cheapest and best.
Patent weather-tight Fastenings and Cill bars for French
casements, which render the French windows perfectly dry, and
make a secure, cheap, and invisible fastening. Improved cramps for
laying floors.
Manufactory for Iron and Brass work of every description. Depôt
for the Patent Wire, Rope, and Sash Line, 69, Princes-street,
Leicester-square.
London:—Printed by Messrs. J. L. Cox & Sons, 75, Great Queen-
street, Lincoln’s-Inn-Fields; and published by Francis Newton,
at the Office, 2, York-street, Covent-garden, where all Letters
and Communications for the Editor are to be addressed.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK THE BUILDER,
NO. 1, DECEMBER 31, 1842 ***

Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.

Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S.


copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in
these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it
in the United States without permission and without paying copyright
royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of
this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™ concept
and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and
may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following the
terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use of
the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for
copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very
easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as
creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research.
Project Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given
away—you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with
eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject
to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution.

START: FULL LICENSE


THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK

To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free


distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or
any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.

Section 1. General Terms of Use and


Redistributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works
1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree
to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be
bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from
the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in
paragraph 1.E.8.

1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be


used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people
who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a
few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic
works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement.
See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.
1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the
collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the
individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the
United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in
the United States and you are located in the United States, we do
not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing,
performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the
work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of
course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™
mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely
sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of
this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name
associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of
this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its
attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without
charge with others.

1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms
of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.

1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:

1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other


immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must
appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™
work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or
with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is
accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed:
This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived


from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a
notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright
holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the
United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must
comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through
1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted


with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted
with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of
this work.

1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project


Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a
part of this work or any other work associated with Project
Gutenberg™.

1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this


electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense
to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means
of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain
Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the
full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.

1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,


performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing


access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:

• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using
the method you already use to calculate your applicable
taxes. The fee is owed to the owner of the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark, but he has agreed to donate
royalties under this paragraph to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty payments must be
paid within 60 days following each date on which you
prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your periodic tax
returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked as
such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4,
“Information about donations to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation.”

• You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who


notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt
that s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project
Gutenberg™ License. You must require such a user to
return or destroy all copies of the works possessed in a
physical medium and discontinue all use of and all access
to other copies of Project Gutenberg™ works.

• You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full


refund of any money paid for a work or a replacement copy,
if a defect in the electronic work is discovered and reported
to you within 90 days of receipt of the work.

• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.

1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™


electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.

1.F.

1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend


considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe
and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating
the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may
be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to,
incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a
copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or
damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.

1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except


for the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph
1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner
of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party
distributing a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this
agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and
expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO
REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF
WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE
FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY
DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE
TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL,
PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE
NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE.

1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you


discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it,
you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by
sending a written explanation to the person you received the work
from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must
return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity
that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a
replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work
electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to
give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in
lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may
demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the
problem.

1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in
paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.

1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied


warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted
by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.

1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the


Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the
Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any
volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution
of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, harmless from all liability,
costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or
indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur:
(a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b)
alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project
Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any Defect you cause.

Section 2. Information about the Mission of


Project Gutenberg™
Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers.
It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and
donations from people in all walks of life.

Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the


assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a
secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help,
see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at
www.gutenberg.org.
Section 3. Information about the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.

The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,


Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact

Section 4. Information about Donations to


the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation
Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without
widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can
be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the
widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small
donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax
exempt status with the IRS.

The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating


charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and
keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in
locations where we have not received written confirmation of
compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of
compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate.

While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where


we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no
prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in
such states who approach us with offers to donate.

International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make


any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.

Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.

Section 5. General Information About Project


Gutenberg™ electronic works
Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project
Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be
freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and
distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of
volunteer support.

Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed


editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in
the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not
necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper
edition.

Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.

This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™,


including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how
to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.

You might also like